Quality And Price
In the late 1960s, a large department store in Madison,
Wisconsin had a special sale on electric knives. Although
they were priced very low, surprisingly, few knives sold.
The store then raised the price a little and the knives
quickly sold out. What could explain this strange
phenomenon, which clearly is not what a demand curve says
should happen?
The most likely explanation for this event is that people
often make judgments about the quality of items based on
their prices. High-quality items usually are expensive and
low-quality items are cheap. Thus, when people see an item
that appears unusually cheap, they suspect that the item has
low quality. In the knives example, people may have thought
that something was wrong with the knives because the price
was so low. When the store raised the price a bit, people no
longer thought that the deal was too good to be true.
Quality often depends on price. For example, consider how
parents would act if they had won a free vacation and had to
hire someone to watch their baby. Would they seek out the
cheapest care available? If they love their baby, they
should be reluctant to act this way. Those who are willing
to work for very little indicate that they are unable to get
higher wages. They will probably provide low-quality child
care. This is a case of adverse
selection.
Suppose, however, that our couple has found someone whom
they trust to watch their baby and are negotiating the
price. Should they try to negotiate for the lowest price
they can get? Maybe not. Maybe the effort the babysitter
will take will depend on how much she is paid. People have
perceptions about what is fair and often work less if paid
less and work harder if paid more.
If all parents find that lowering price decreases the
quality of services they get, then even if there is a
surplus of people wanting work as babysitters, price may not
decline. Such a market would not act as supply and demand
suggests, but would have an equilibrium price that is not
market-clearing.
A number of economists have argued that this influence of
price on quality is important in labor markets and have
called the prices or wages in these markets "efficiency
wages." The wage is efficient not in the sense of
economic
efficiency, but in the sense that it is the best price
from the viewpoint of individual buyers or sellers in the
market. The babysitting case mentioned previously has two
reasons that an employer might prefer to pay a price higher
than the market demands. A third reason can exist if higher
wages cut turnover. If time is needed to train employees,
then high rates of turnover cut productivity. Hence high
wages, not low wages, may result in the lowest costs for the
employer.
A similar situation may exist in the market for loanable
funds. Banks are major sellers in this market. Suppose that
there is a decrease in the supply of funds that they have to
lend. A supply and demand model suggests that price, which
in this market is the interest rate, will rise and force out
some of those who want to borrow money. Banks, however, have
to wonder what sort of customer is left at high interest
rates. Perhaps there is a problem of adverse selection, that
higher interest rates leave only those borrowers who are
willing to take big risks. If higher interest rates increase
the riskiness of the loans the bank makes, it may find that
the higher default rates reduce profits. In this case, the
bank will find that the best course of action will be to
limit the rise in its interest rates and ration funds among
borrowers. In this market, there will be a shortage of funds
at the equilibrium price. The bank will tell some people
willing to pay the interest rate that they cannot borrow
because the bank does not have funds available.
Efficiency wages (and prices and interest rates) are
important when one looks at how economic systems adjust to
equilibrium. This topic has been of considerable interest in
macroeconomics, where adjustment problems are considered
more seriously than they are in microeconomics.
We finish this set of reading by looking at dangers in auctions.
Copyright
Robert Schenk
|